Queen's University Economics Department
Economics 320A - Macroeconomic Theory II
Fall 1998
Partial solutions
Question 1.6
Let
a = 4/5, then uht = 1.342 y0.5 for t ³ 1 and ch0(1) = 0.2 y.
Let
a = 1/5, then uht = 1.342 y0.5 for t ³ 1 and ch0(1) = 0.8 y.
Let
a = 1/2, then uht = 1.414 y0.5 for t ³ 1 and ch0(1) = 0.5 y.
The allocation with
a = 1/2 is Pareto superior to the allocation with
a = 4/5. When
a = 1/2, members of generations t ³ 1 enjoy more
utility and the
old people in period 1 have more consumption of the time 1 good. The
allocation
a = 1/2 is actually Pareto optimal.
The allocation with
a = 1/5 is Pareto superior to the allocation with
a = 4/5. When
a = 1/5, members of generations t ³ 1 enjoy as
much utility and the
old people in period 1 have more consumption of the time 1 good.
The allocation with
a = 1/2 is not Pareto comparable to the allocation with
a = 1/5. Members of generations t ³ 1 enjoy more utility when
a = 1/2 whereas the
old people in period 1 have more consumption of the time 1 good when
a = 1/5.
Question 2.2
sht(r(t)) = |
b2 r(t) wth(t)
1+b2 r(t)
|
- |
wht(t+1)
r(t) (1+b2 r(t))
|
|
|
Question 2.3
(a) St(r(t)) = 100-50 r(t)
(b) St(r(t)) = 75-50 r(t)
Question 2.4
(a) The competitive equilibrium is the set of interest rates r(t) = 0.5 for
t ³ 1 and the consumption allocation
c01(1) = 1 for h = 1,..., 100 |
|
cth(t) = 2 for h = 1,..., 100 and for t ³ 1 |
|
ct-1h(t) = 1 for h = 1,..., 100 and for t ³ 1 |
|
(b) The competitive equilibrium is the set of interest rates r(t) = 2 for
t ³ 1 and the consumption allocation
c01(1) = 2 for h = 1,..., 100 |
|
cth(t) = 1 for h = 1,..., 100 and for t ³ 1 |
|
ct-1h(t) = 2 for h = 1,..., 100 and for t ³ 1 |
|
(c) Same as (a).
(d) The competitive equilibrium is the set of interest rates r(t) = 2/3 for
t ³ 1 and the consumption allocation
c01(1) = 1 for h = 1,..., 100 |
|
cth(t) = 1.75 for h = 2, 4,..., 100 and for t ³ 1 |
|
cth(t) = 1.25 for h = 1, 3,..., 99 and for t ³ 1 |
|
ct-1h(t) = 1.1667 for h = 2, 4,..., 100 and for t ³ 1 |
|
ct-1h(t) = 0.8333 for h = 1, 3,..., 99 and for t ³ 1 |
|
(e) The competitive equilibrium is the set of interest rates r(t) = 0.625 for
t ³ 1 and the consumption allocation
c01(1) = 1 for h = 1,..., 100 |
|
cth(t) = 1.8 for h = 1,..., 60 and for t ³ 1 |
|
cth(t) = 1.3 for h = 61,..., 100 and for t ³ 1 |
|
ct-1h(t) = 1.125 for h = 1,..., 60 and for t ³ 1 |
|
ct-1h(t) = 0.8125 for h = 61,..., 100 and for t ³ 1 |
|
(f) The competitive equilibrium is the set of interest rates r(t) = 1 for
t odd and r(t) = 1/2 for t even and the consumption allocation
Period 1: ch1(1) = 1 and c0h(1) = 1 for h = 1, ..., 100.
Period 2: ch2(2) = 2 and c1h(2) = 1 for h = 1, ..., 100.
Period 3: ch3(3) = 1 and c2h(3) = 1 for h = 1, ..., 100.
Periods 4, 6, ... : like period 2.
Periods 5, 7, ... : like period 3.
Question 3.1
(a)
The competitive equilibrium without scheme is a set of interest rates
{r(1), r(2), r(3), ...} = {1/2, 1/2, ...} |
|
a consumption allocation
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ...} = {2, 2, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ...} = {1, 1, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
and a government policy
{th1(1), th2(2), th3(3), ...} = {0, 0, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
{th0(1), th1(2), th2(3), ...} = {0, 0, ...} h = 1, ..., 100. |
|
A period 1 old (who is member of generation 0) consumes 1 unit (ch0(1) = 1).
A typical member of generations t = 1, 2, 3, ... has utility
uht = cht(t) cht(t+1) = 2×1 = 2.
The competitive equilibrium with scheme is a set of interest rates
{r(1), r(2), r(3), ...} = {2, 2, ...} |
|
a consumption allocation
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ...} = {1, 1, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ...} = {2, 2, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
and a government policy
{th1(1), th2(2), th3(3), ...} = {1, 1, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
{th0(1), th1(2), th2(3), ...} = {-1, -1, ...} h = 1, ..., 100. |
|
A period 1 old (who is member of generation 0) consumes 2 units (ch0(1) = 2).
A typical member of generations t = 1, 2, 3, ... has utility
uht = cht(t) cht(t+1) = 1×2 = 2. Members of generation 0 are better off
(higher consumption) with the scheme and members of generations 1, 2, ...
are neither better off nor worse off (same level of utility). Therefore, the competitive equilibrium with
scheme is Pareto superior.
(b)
The competitive equilibrium without scheme is a set of interest rates
{r(1), r(2), r(3), ...} = {2/3, 2/3, ...} |
|
a consumption allocation
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ...} = {1.75, 1.75, ...} h = 2, 4, ..., 100 |
|
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ...} = {1.25, 1.25, ...} h = 1, 3, ..., 99 |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ...} = {1, 1.1667, 1.1667 ...} h = 2, 4, ... 100 |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ...} = {1, 0.8333, 0.8333 ...} h = 1, 3, ... 99 |
|
and a government policy
{th1(1), th2(2), th3(3), ...} = {0, 0, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
{th0(1), th1(2), th2(3), ...} = {0, 0, ...} h = 1, ..., 100. |
|
A period 1 old (who is member of generation 0) consumes 1 unit (ch0(1) = 1).
A typical member of generations t = 1, 2, 3, ... has utility
uht = cht(t) cht(t+1) = 1.75×1.1667 = 2.0417 for h even and
uht = cht(t) cht(t+1) = 1.25×0.8333 = 1.0416 for h odd.
The competitive equilibrium with scheme is a set of interest rates
{r(1), r(2), r(3), ...} = {4, 4, ...} |
|
a consumption allocation
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ...} = {0.75, 0.75, ...} h = 2, 4, ..., 100 |
|
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ...} = {0.25, 0.25, ...} h = 1, 2, ..., 99 |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ...} = {2, 3, 3 ...} h = 2, 4, ... 100 |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ...} = {2, 1, 1 ...} h = 1, 3, ... 99 |
|
and a government policy
{th1(1), th2(2), th3(3), ...} = {1, 1, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
{th0(1), th1(2), th2(3), ...} = {-1, -1, ...} h = 1, ..., 100. |
|
A period 1 old (who is member of generation 0) consumes 2 units (ch0(1) = 2).
A typical member of generations t = 1, 2, 3, ... has utility
uht = cht(t) cht(t+1) = 0.75×3 = 2.25 for h even and
uht = cht(t) cht(t+1) = 0.25×1 = 0.25 for h odd. These allocations
are not Pareto comparable since period 1 old (higher consumption) and even members of generations t = 1, 2, ...
are better off (higher utility) and odd members of generations t = 1, 2, ... are worse off (lower utility).
(c)
The competitive equilibrium without scheme is a set of interest rates
{r(1), r(2), r(3), ...} = {1/2, 1/2, ...} |
|
a consumption allocation
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ...} = {2, 2, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ...} = {1, 1, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
and a government policy
{th1(1), th2(2), th3(3), ...} = {0, 0, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
{th0(1), th1(2), th2(3), ...} = {0, 0, ...} h = 1, ..., 100. |
|
A period 1 old (who is member of generation 0) consumes 1 unit (ch0(1) = 1).
A typical member of generations t = 1, 2, 3, ... has utility
uht = cht(t) cht(t+1) = 2×1 = 2.
The competitive equilibrium with scheme is a set of interest rates
{r(1), r(2), r(3), ...} = {3, 3, ...} |
|
a consumption allocation
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ...} = {1, 1, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ...} = {3, 3, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
and a government policy
{th1(1), th2(2), th3(3), ...} = {1, 1, ...} h = 1, ..., 100 |
|
{th0(1), th1(2), th2(3), ...} = {-2, -2, ...} h = 1, ..., 100. |
|
A period 1 old (who is member of generation 0) consumes 3 units (ch0(1) = 3).
A typical member of generations t = 1, 2, 3, ... has utility
uht = cht(t) cht(t+1) = 1×3 = 3. Members of generation 0 are better off
(higher consumption) with the scheme and members of generations 1, 2, ...
are also better off (higher utility). Therefore, the competitive equilibrium with
scheme is Pareto superior.
(c)
Let's take the example of the Canadian Pension Plan.
Suppose the Canadian government commits to transfer 2 units of good to any old person in
any period. During the first 10 periods, the number of young (workers) paying
taxes is always twice as large as the number of old (retired) receiving
transfers. So in periods 1 to 10, we have an equilibrium as in part (c) and
members of generations 1 to 10 enjoy a utility level of 3. However, in periods
10 and following, the generation size stops growing and the ratio of young to old
is now 1:1. The young must pay alot more taxes to support this relatively large
number of old. The effect is that members of generations 11, 12 and so on
have lower utility (uht = 0) than members of generations 1 to 10. As the ratio of young to
old Canadian people decreases, the federal government might have to reduce benefits
for CPP so that it does not impose too high a tax burden on the working young.
Question 5.3
The time t temporary equilibrium is the interest rate r(t) = 3/2, the bond
price pk(t) = 2/3 and members of generation t consumption cht(t) = 4/3 "h
and cht(t+1) = 2 "h.
Question 5.4
The time t temporary equilibrium is the interest rate r(t) = 1, the bond
price pk(t) = 1/2 and members of generation t consumption cht(t) = 1.5 "h
and cht(t+1) = 1.5 "h.
Question 5.6
The perfect foresight competitive equilibrium for this economy is the set of interest
rates
{r(1), r(2), ... } = {0.8333, 0.75, 0.5714, 0.5, ... }, |
|
the set of bond prices
{p2(1), p1(2), p0(3)} = {1.6, 1.3333, 1}, |
|
the consumption allocation
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ...} = { 1.6, 1.6667, 1.75, 2, ... } "h |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ...} = { 1.4, 1.3333, 1.25, 1, ... } "h |
|
and the government policy
{ G(1), G(2), G(3),... } = {0, ... } |
|
{th1(1), th2(2), ... } = {0, 0, 0.25, 0, ... } "h |
|
{th0(1), th1(2), ... } = {-0.4, 0, 0, 0, ... } "h |
|
{ B2(1), B1(2) } = { 25, 25 }. |
|
Question 5.7
The perfect foresight competitive equilibrium for this economy is the set of interest
rates
{r(1), r(2), ... } = {0.9, 0.625, 0.5, ... }, |
|
the set of bond prices
{p2(1), p1(2), p0(3)} = {1.7778, 1.6, 1}, |
|
the consumption allocation
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ...} = { 1.5556, 1.6, 2, ... } "h |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ...} = { 1.4445, 1.4, 1.25, 1, ... } "h |
|
and the government policy
{ G(1), G(2), G(3),... } = {0, ... } |
|
{th1(1), th2(2), ... } = {0, 0, 0.25, 0, ... } "h |
|
{th0(1), th1(2), ... } = {-0.4445, 0, 0, 0, ... } "h |
|
{ B2(1), B1(2) } = { 25, 25 }. |
|
Comparing the policies in question 5.6 and 5.7, Ricardian Equivalence does not
hold because different generations pay off the debt.
Question 5.8
The perfect foresight competitive equilibrium for this economy is the set of interest
rates
{r(1), r(2), ... } = {0.6667, 0.6, 0.5263, 5, ... }, |
|
the set of bond prices
{p2(1), p1(2), p0(3)} = {2.5, 1.6667, 1}, |
|
the consumption allocation
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ...} = { 1.75, 1.8333, 1.9, 2 ... } "h |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ...} = { 1.25, 1.6667, 1.1, 1, ... } "h |
|
and the government policy
{ G(1), G(2), G(3),... } = {0, ... } |
|
{th1(1), th2(2), ... } = {0, 0, 0.10, 0, ... } "h |
|
{th0(1), th1(2), ... } = {-0.25, 0, 0, 0, ... } "h |
|
{ B2(1), B1(2) } = { 10, 10 }. |
|
Question 5.11
The perfect foresight competitive equilibrium for this economy is the set of interest
rates
{r(1), r(2), ... } = {0.6667, 0.6, 0.5263, 5, ... }, |
|
the set of bond prices
{p(1), p(2) } = {1.5, 1.6667 }, |
|
the consumption allocation
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ...} = { 1.75, 1.8333, 1.9, 2 ... } "h |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ...} = { 1.25, 1.6667, 1.1, 1, ... } "h |
|
and the government policy
{ G(1), G(2), G(3),... } = {0, ... } |
|
{th1(1), th2(2), ... } = {0, 0, 0.10, 0, ... } "h |
|
{th0(1), th1(2), ... } = {-0.25, 0, 0, 0, ... } "h |
|
{ B(1), B(2) } = { 16.6667, 10 }. |
|
Comparing 5.11 and 5.8, we have different patterns of government borrowing but same interest
rates, consumption allocation and taxes/transfers. This is an example of irrelevance
of maturity composition.
Back to main page
File translated from TEX by TTH, version 1.65.