Solutions to assignment 2
Solutions to Assignment 2
Question 1
(a)
Number of young |
110 |
121 |
133 |
133 |
133 |
Number of old |
100 |
110 |
121 |
133 |
133 |
(b) Total transfer in period t = Number of old (N(t-1)) times
transfer per old person (0.2).
Total transfer |
20 |
22 |
24.2 |
26.6 |
26.6 |
(c) All people are identical within a generation and the government
balances its budget. In such an economy, there is no trade and each person
simply consumes his endowment minus (plus) tax (transfer).
Generation 0: ch0(1) = wh0(1)-th0(1) = 1-(-0.2) = 1.2
Generation 1:
ch1(1) = wh1(1)-th1(1) = 2-0.2727 = 1.7273
ch1(2) = wh1(2)-th1(2) = 1-(-0.2) = 1.2
Generation 2:
ch2(2) = wh2(2)-th2(2) = 2-0.2231 = 1.7769
ch2(3) = wh2(3)-th2(3) = 1-(-0.2) = 1.2
Generation 3:
ch3(3) = wh3(3)-th3(3) = 2-0.1820 = 1.818
ch3(4) = wh3(4)-th3(4) = 1-(-0.2) = 1.2
Generation 4:
ch4(4) = wh4(4)-th4(4) = 2-0.2 = 1.8
ch4(5) = wh4(5)-th4(5) = 1-(-0.2) = 1.2
Generation 5:
ch5(5) = wh5(5)-th5(5) = 2-0.2 = 1.8
ch5(6) = wh5(6)-th5(6) = 1-(-0.2) = 1.2
(d)
r(1) = |
ch1(2)
ch1(1)
|
= |
1.2
1.7273
|
= 0.6947 |
|
r(2) = |
ch2(3)
ch2(2)
|
= |
1.2
1.7769
|
= 0.6753 |
|
r(3) = |
ch3(4)
ch3(3)
|
= |
1.2
1.818
|
= 0.6601 |
|
r(4) = |
ch4(5)
ch4(4)
|
= |
1.2
1.8
|
= |
2
3
|
|
|
r(5) = |
ch5(6)
ch5(5)
|
= |
1.2
1.8
|
= |
2
3
|
|
|
(e)
The competitive equilibrium is the set of interest rates
{r(1), r(2), r(3), r(4), ... } = {0.6947, 0.6753, 0.6601, 0.6667, ... }, |
|
the consumption allocation
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ... } = { 1.7273, 1.7769, 1.818, 1.8, ... } "h |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ... } = { 1.2, ... } "h, |
|
and the government policy
{G(1), G(2), G(3), ... } = {10, 5, 0, ... } |
|
{th1(1), th2(2), th3(3), ... } = { 0.2727, 0.2231, 0.1820, 0.2, ... } "h |
|
{th0(1), th1(2), th2(3), ... } = { -0.2, ... } "h. |
|
Question 2
(a)
young: cht(t) = wht(t)-tht(t)-lh(t)-p(t) bh(t)
old: cht(t+1) = wht(t+1)-tht(t+1)+r(t) lh(t)+bh(t)
The easiest way to derive the lifetime budget constraint is to divide the
budget constraint when old and add it to the one when young. Anyhow, the constraint is
cht(t)+ |
cht(t+1)
r(t)
|
= wht(t)-tht(t)+ |
wht(t+1)-tht(t-1)
r(t)
|
+bh(t) |
é ê
ë
|
|
1
r(t)
|
-p(t) |
ù ú
û
|
|
|
Imposing the present value condition 1/r(t)-p(t) = 0 we get
cht(t)+ |
cht(t+1)
r(t)
|
= wht(t)-tht(t)+ |
wht(t+1)-tht(t-1)
r(t)
|
|
|
Where does the present value condition come from? Suppose r(t) < 1/p(t), then
the interest rate on private borrowing and lending is less than the return on government bonds.
Therefore the agent wants to borrow an infinite amount on the private borrowing/lending market
and sets bh(t)®¥ to make a riskless infinite profit. But that cannot
be an equilibrium because there is no lender on the private borrowing/lending market.
Suppose r(t) > 1/p(t), then
the interest rate on private borrowing and lending is greater than the return on government bonds.
Therefore the agent wants to lend an infinite amount on the private borrowing/lending market
and sets bh(t)® -¥ to make a riskless infinite profit.
But we restrict bh(t) to be nonnegative, so the best the agent can do is
set bh(t) = 0. So we have a situation where the government wishes to sell bonds
but where no private agent wants to buy these bonds. That cannot be an equilibrium.
Therefore, the only possible case is r(t) = 1/p(t).
(b)
Time t good market clearing
|
N(t) å
h = 1
|
cht(t)+ |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
cht-1(t)+G(t) = |
N(t) å
h = 1
|
wht(t)+ |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
wht-1(t) |
|
Summing the time t old budget constraint yields
|
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
cht-1(t) = |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
wht-1(t)- |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
tht-1(t)+r(t-1) |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
lh(t-1)+ |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
bh(t-1) |
|
Substituting in time t good market clearing we have
|
|
+ |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
wht-1(t)- |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
tht-1(t)+r(t-1) |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
lh(t-1)+ |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
bh(t-1) |
| |
+G(t) = |
N(t) å
h = 1
|
wht(t)+ |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
wht-1(t) |
|
| |
|
Imposing market clearing on private borring/lending market,
åh = 1N(t-1)lh(t-1) = 0, we have
|
N(t) å
h = 1
|
cht(t)- |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
tht-1(t)+ |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
bh(t-1)+G(t) = |
N(t) å
h = 1
|
wht(t) |
|
rewriting the government budget constraint as
- |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
tht-1(t) = |
N(t) å
h = 1
|
tht(t)+p(t) B(t)-G(t)-B(t-1) |
|
and substituting it in the previous equation we get
|
N(t) å
h = 1
|
cht(t)+ |
N(t) å
h = 1
|
tht(t)+p(t) B(t)-G(t)-B(t-1)+ |
N(t-1) å
h = 1
|
bh(t-1)+G(t) = |
N(t) å
h = 1
|
wht(t) |
|
imposing market clearing on the government bonds market,
åh = 1N(t-1)bh(t-1) = B(t-1) we get
|
N(t) å
h = 1
|
cht(t)+ |
N(t) å
h = 1
|
tht(t)+p(t) B(t) = |
N(t) å
h = 1
|
wht(t) |
|
imposing utility maximization, cht(t) = cht(r(t))
we finally get
St(r(t)) = |
N(t) å
h = 1
|
[wht(t)-cht(r(t))-tht(t)] = p(t) B(t) |
|
(c)
This is an economy with identical agents within each generation and where the
government balances its budget in every period. therefore the methodology
of question 1 can be used to solve for the competitive equilibrium. Alternatively,
we can impose the conditions S1(r(1)) = 0, S2(r(2)) = 0 and so on to solve for the equilibrium interest rates
and then plug those in the consumption and savings functions to get consumption
when young and when old. Anyhow, the competitive equilibrium is the set of
interest rates
{r(1), r(2), r(3), r(4), ... } = {0.5398, 0.5398, 0.5263, ... }, |
|
the consumption allocation
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ... } = { 1.95, 1.95, 2, ... } "h |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ... } = { 1, ... } "h, |
|
and the government policy
{G(1), G(2), G(3), ... } = {5, 5, 0, ... } |
|
{th1(1), th2(2), th3(3), ... } = { 0.05, 0.05, 0, ... } "h |
|
{th0(1), th1(2), th2(3), ... } = { 0, ... } "h. |
|
(d)
The agregate savings function is
St(r(t)) = 48.7179 (2- tht(t)) - |
51.2821 (1-tht(t+1))
r(t)
|
. |
|
Period 1: S1 = 5, no taxes on members of generation 1.
S1(r(1)) = 5 Þ 97.4358- |
51.2821
r(1)
|
= 5 Þ r(1) = 0.5548 |
|
The price of a government bond is p(1) = 1/0.5548 = 1.8025. Therefore the government
issues B(1) = 5/p(1) = 2.774 bonds in order to collect 5 units of the time 1 good
for its own consumption.
Period 2: S2 = 5+2.774, no taxes on members of generation 2.
S2(r(2)) = 7.774 Þ 97.4358- |
51.2821
r(2)
|
= 7.774 Þ r(2) = 0.5720 |
|
The price of a government bond is p(2) = 1/0.5720 = 1.7484. Therefore the government
issues B(2) = 7.774/p(2) = 4.446 bonds in order to collect 5 units of the time 2 good
for its own consumption and 2.774 units of the time 2 good to pay off its debt.
Period 3: S3 = 0, no government borrowing, taxes on members of generation 3.
The tax on a member of generation 3 (when young) is B(2)/100. Therefore
th3(3) = 0.04446.
S3(r(3)) = 0 Þ 95.2698- |
51.2821
r(3)
|
= 0 Þ r(3) = 0.5383 |
|
Period 4: S4 = 0, no government borrowing, no taxes on members of generation 4.
S4(r(4)) = 0 Þ 97.4358- |
51.2821
r(4)
|
= 0 Þ r(4) = 0.5263 |
|
The competitive equilibrium is the set of interest rates
{r(1), r(2), r(3), r(4), ... } = {0.5548, 0.5719, 0.5383, 0.5263 ... }, |
|
the consumption allocation
{ch1(1), ch2(2), ch3(3), ... } = { 1.95, 1.9223, 1.9555, 2, ... } "h |
|
{ch0(1), ch1(2), ch2(3), ... } = { 1, 1.0277, 1.0444, 1, ... } "h, |
|
and the government policy
{G(1), G(2), G(3), ... } = {5, 5, 0, ... } |
|
{B(1), B(2), B(3), ... } = {2.7739, 4.4463, 0, ... } |
|
{th1(1), th2(2), th3(3), ... } = { 0, 0, 0.04446, 0, ... } "h |
|
{th0(1), th1(2), th2(3), ... } = { 0, ... } "h. |
|
· We see that government actions raise the interest rate in
periods 1, 2
and 3. In periods 1 and 2, government consumption and borrowing raises the
interest rate compared to a situation where there are no government
actions (like in period 4). Government consumption leaves less unit
available to the private sector in periods 1 and 2. The relative scarcity of
time 1 and 2 goods increases r(1) and r(2).
· We can also explain the high interest rates in periods 1 and 2
using a savings story. Since the government wants to sell B(1) bonds in
period 1, people have to save more to buy these bonds. By making the
interest rate higher, the invisible hand makes sure people are going to save
more. Since the government borrows even more in period 2, the invisible hand
raises the interest rate even more to generate more savings.
· In period 3, government taxation is responsible for the relatively
high interest rate (compared to r(4)). We explain this higher interest
rate by decomposing the total effect on savings of a change in taxes. The
first effect is the direct effect of taxation on savings holding the interest
rate constant. Analytically we have
|
¶sht(r(t))
¶tht(t)
|
|
ê ê
ê
|
r(t) constant
|
= |
-b
1+b
|
= -0.4872 < 0. |
|
So, the direct effect of taxes is to reduce savings. But that is not the end
of the story because the aggregate savings are now negative, which does not
satisfy the equilibrium condition St = 0. This lower level of savings
pushes the interest rate up. Think of the private borrowing/lending market.
When people save less that means lenders have fewer units to
supply on the private borrowing/lending market and borrowers demand more
units. The two effects work together to increase the interest rate. The
larger interest rate is such that St = 0.
Numerically we have the following. When there are no taxes (like in period
4), the interest rate is 0.5263 and sht(0.5263) = 0. When we introduce
taxes tht(t) = 0.04446 we have
sht(0.5263) |
ê ê
|
r(t) constant
|
= |
0.95 (2-0.044446)
1.95
|
- |
1-0
1.95 ×0.5263
|
= -0.0217 |
|
So the tax effect reduces savings by 0.0217. When we let the interest rate
adjust, we get the new equilibrium level of savings
sht(0.5383) = |
0.95 (2-0.044446)
1.95
|
- |
1-0
1.95 ×0.5383
|
= 0 |
|
So the tax effect reduces savings by 0.0217 and the interest rate effect
increases savings by 0.0217. The total effect on savings is zero but the
interest rate is larger.
(e)
In part (c), members of generations 1 and 2 pay taxes to finance government consumption
in periods 1 and 2. In part (d), members of generation 3 pay taxes to finance
government consumption in periods 1 and 2 and members of generations
1 and 2 do not pay any taxes. Therefore, the present value of total tax liability
of members of generations 1, 2 and 3 in part (d) is different from the
one in part (c). In such a case, Ricardian equivalence of debt and taxes fails.
Back to main page
File translated from TEX by TTH, version 1.65.